|
In economics, the term microfoundations refers to the microeconomic analysis of the behavior of individual agents such as households or firms that underpins a macroeconomic theory (Barro, 1993, Glossary, p. 594).〔Robert J. Barro (1993), ''Macroeconomics'', 4th ed. ISBN 0-471-57543-7.〕〔Maarten Janssen (2008), '(Microfoundations )', in ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd ed.〕 Most early macroeconomic models, including early Keynesian models, were based on hypotheses about relationships between aggregate quantities, such as aggregate output, employment, consumption, and investment. Critics and proponents of these models disagreed as to whether these aggregate relationships were consistent with the principles of microeconomics.〔• E. Roy Weintraub (1977). "The Microfoundations of Macroeconomics: A Critical Survey," ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 15(1), pp. (1-23 ). • _____ (1979). '' Microfoundations: The Compatibility of Microeconomics and Macroeconomics'', Cambridge. (Description ) and (preview. )〕 Therefore, in recent decades macroeconomists have attempted to combine microeconomic models of household and firm behavior to derive the relationships between macroeconomic variables. Today, many macroeconomic models, representing different theoretical points of view,〔• Thomas Cooley, ed., (1995), ''Frontiers of Business Cycle Research,'' Princeton University Press. (Description ) and (preview ). ISBN 0-691-04323-X. • Michael Woodford (2003), ''Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, '' Princeton University Press. (Description ) and (Table of Contents ). ISBN 0-691-01049-8.〕 are derived by aggregating microeconomic models, allowing economists to test them both with macroeconomic and microeconomic data. ==History== Critics of the Keynesian approach to macroeconomics soon pointed out that some of Keynes' assumptions were inconsistent with standard microeconomics. For example, Milton Friedman's microeconomic theory of consumption over time (the 'permanent income hypothesis') suggested that the marginal propensity to consume out of temporary income, which is crucial for the Keynesian multiplier, was likely to be much smaller than Keynesians assumed. For this reason, many empirical studies have attempted to measure the marginal propensity to consume (Barro, 1993, Ch. 3, p. 87), and macroeconomists have also studied alternative microeconomic models (such as models of credit market imperfections and precautionary saving) that might imply a higher marginal propensity to consume.〔Angus Deaton (1992), ''Understanding Consumption'', Oxford University Press. (Description ) and chapter-preview (links ). ISBN 0-19-828824-7.〕 One particularly influential call for microfoundations was Robert Lucas, Jr.'s critique of traditional macroeconometric forecasting models. After the apparent shift of the Phillips curve relationship in the 1970s, Lucas argued that the correlations between aggregate variables observed in macroeconomic data would tend to change whenever macroeconomic policy changed. This implied that microfounded models are more appropriate for predicting the impact of policy changes, under the assumption that changes in macroeconomic policy do not alter the underlying microeconomic structure of the macroeconomy.〔( 'The Smets-Wouters model': ECB webpage with discussion of advantages of microfounded macroeconomic models )〕 抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)』 ■ウィキペディアで「Microfoundations」の詳細全文を読む スポンサード リンク
|